Relative Income Hypothesis
Relative Income Hypothesis
Relative income hypothesis states that the satisfaction (or utility) an individual derives from a given consumption level depends on its relative magnitude in the society (e.g., relative to the average consumption) rather than its absolute level. It is based on a postulate that has long been acknowledged by psychologists and sociologists, namely that individuals care about status. In economics, relative income hypothesis is attributed to James Duesenberry, who investigated the implications of this idea for consumption behavior in his 1949 book titled Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior.
At the time when Duesenberry wrote his book the dominant theory of consumption was the one developed by the English economist John Maynard Keynes, which was based on the hypothesis that individuals consume a decreasing, and save an increasing, percentage of their income as their income increases. This was indeed the pattern observed in cross-sectional consumption data: At a given point in time the rich in the population saved a higher fraction of their income than the poor did. However, Keynesian theory was contradicted by another empirical regularity: Aggregate saving rate did not grow over time as aggregate income grew. Duesenberry argued that relative income hypothesis could account for both the cross-sectional and time series evidence.
Duesenberry claimed that an individual’s utility index depended on the ratio of his or her consumption to a weighted average of the consumption of the others. From this he drew two conclusions: (1) aggregate saving rate is independent of aggregate income, which is consistent with the time series evidence; and (2) the propensity to save of an individual is an increasing function of his or her percentile position in the income distribution, which is consistent with the cross-sectional evidence.
Despite its intuitive and empirical appeal Duesenberry’s theory has not found wide acceptance and has been dominated by the life-cycle/permanent-income hypothesis of Franco Modigliani and Richard Brumberg (published in 1954) and Milton Friedman (1957). These closely related theories implied that consumption is an increasing function of the expected lifetime resources of an individual and could account for both the cross-sectional and time series evidence previously mentioned. However, starting with the 1970s, inability of these theories to explain some other puzzling empirical observations as well as the increasing evidence that people indeed seem to care about relative income have generated renewed interest in relative income hypothesis.
The first piece of evidence was presented in 1974 by Richard Easterlin, who found that self-reported happiness of individuals (i.e., subjective well-being) varies directly with income at a given point in time but average well-being tends to be highly stable over time despite tremendous income growth. Easterlin argued that these patterns are consistent with the claim that an individual’s well-being depends mostly on relative income rather than absolute income. Subsequent research, such as that published by Andrew Oswald in 1997, has accumulated abundant evidence in support of this claim.
Relative income hypothesis has also found some corroboration from indirect macroeconomic evidence. One of these is the observation that higher growth rates lead to higher saving rates, which is inconsistent with the life-cycle/permanent-income theory since the lifetime resources of an individual increases as growth rate increases. The work of Christopher Carroll, Jody Overland, and David N. Weil explains this observation with a growth model in which preferences depend negatively on the past consumption of the individual or on the past average consumption in the economy that is under the relative income hypothesis.
Another empirical observation that has been problematic for the life-cycle/permanent-income theory is the equity premium puzzle, which states that the observed difference between the return on equity and the return on riskless assets is too large to be explained by a plausible specification of the theory. Introducing past average consumption into the preferences accounts for this observation much better.
Relative income hypothesis has other important economic implications. Perhaps the most obvious implication is that consumption creates negative externalities in the society, which are not taken into account in individual decision-making. If individuals consume, and therefore work, to increase their status, then they will tend to work too much relative to the socially optimal level and hence income taxation could improve the social welfare.
Relative income hypothesis is a special case of negatively interdependent preferences according to which individuals care about both their absolute and relative material payoffs. In 2000 Levent Koçkesen, Efe Ok, and Rajiv Sethi showed that negatively interdependent preferences yield a higher material payoff than do selfish preferences in many strategic environments, which implies that evolution will tend to favor the emergence of negatively interdependent preferences. This could be regarded as one explanation for the empirical support behind relative income hypothesis.
SEE ALSO Absolute Income Hypothesis; Consumption; Life-Cycle Hypothesis; Microfoundations; Modigliani-Miller Theorems; Permanent Income Hypothesis
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Abel, Andrew B. 1990. Asset Prices under Habit Formation and Catching Up with the Joneses. American Economic Review 80 (2): 38-42.
Boskin, Michael J., and Eytan Sheshinski. 1978. Optimal Redistributive Taxation when Individual Welfare Depends upon Relative Income. Quarterly Journal of Economics 92 (4): 589-601.
Campbell, John Y., and John H. Cochrane. 1999. By Force of Habit: A Consumption-Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior. Journal of Political Economy 107 (2): 205-251.
Carroll, Christopher D., Jody Overland, and David N. Weil. 1997. Comparison Utility in a Growth Model. Journal of Economic Growth 2 (4): 339-367.
Carroll, Christopher D., Jody Overland, and David N. Weil. 2000. Saving and Growth with Habit Formation. American Economic Review 90 (3): 341-355.
Duesenberry, James S. 1949. Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Easterlin, Richard. 1974. Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence. In Nations and Households in Economic Growth, ed. Paul A. David and Melvin W. Reder. New York: Academic Press.
Friedman, Milton. 1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Koçkesen, Levent, Efe A. Ok, and Rajiv Sethi. 2000. The Strategic Advantage of Negatively Interdependent Preferences. Journal of Economic Theory 92 (2): 274-299.
Modigliani, Franco, and Richard Brumberg. 1954. Utility Analysis and the Consumption Function: An Interpretation of Cross-Section Data. In Post-Keynesian Economics, ed. Kenneth K. Kurihara. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press.
Oswald, Andrew J. 1997. Happiness and Economic Performance. Economic Journal 107 (November): 1815-1831.
Levent Koçkesen